Skip to main content

Economic liberalisation and the mobility of minority groups: evidence from Māori in New Zealand

Abstract

Between 1984 and 1993, New Zealand undertook comprehensive market-oriented economic reforms. In this paper, we use census data to examine how the internal mobility of Māori compares to that of Europeans in New Zealand in the period after these reforms. It is often suggested that Māori are less mobile than other ethnic groups because of attachment to particular geographical locations. If this were the case, Māori may have been disadvantaged in the post-reform period because they were more likely to be living in adversely affected areas and less likely to move to pursue better employment opportunities. In contrast to the anecdotal evidence, we find that Māori are more mobile on average than similar Europeans. However, Māori who live in areas with strong networks of their iwi are slightly less mobile than Europeans. The difference between Māori who live locally to their iwi and those who do not is even more pronounced when we consider responsiveness to local labour market shocks. Non-local Māori are considerably more responsive to changes in economic opportunities than are Europeans, whereas local Māori are almost entirely unresponsive.

JEL codes: J61, J15, R23.

1 Introduction

The 1980s marked a time of structural adjustment around the world. New Zealand began the decade as one of the most regulated economies in the OECD. By 1984, it was facing unsustainable fiscal and current account deficits and high inflation and foreign debt. This triggered a period of comprehensive market-oriented economic reforms that lasted until 1993. Between 1984 and 1991, real per capita GDP growth averaged 0.4 % and unemployment rose from 5 % in 1984 to almost 11 % in 1992. These reforms had particularly severe negative impacts on Māori and Pacific Islanders, who were disproportionately employed in low-skilled manufacturing jobs that largely disappeared with the end of industry support and import restrictions.

In this paper, we use census data to examine how the internal mobility of Māori compares to that of Europeans in New Zealand in the period after these reforms. It is often suggested that Māori are less mobile than other ethnic groups because of attachment to particular geographical locations (Walker, 1990). If this were the case, Māori may have been disadvantaged in the post-reform period because they were more likely to be living in adversely affected areas and less likely to move to pursue better employment opportunities (Sin and Stillman, 2005). Furthermore, Māori had (and still have) lower average levels of educational attainment than Europeans, making transitioning to new careers particularly difficult. Previous research has found that the reforms of the 1980s had large persistent effects on local communities, suggesting that their impact on individuals could have also been long lasting (Stillman, Velamuri and Aitken 2010; Karagedikli et al., 2000; Dixon, 1998).

Our regression analysis compares the mobility between geographic labour markets of Māori and Europeans who initially live in the same area. We also examine heterogeneity in outcomes within the Māori population, distinguishing Māori who report only one ethnicity from those with multiple ethnicities and those who report a tribal (iwi) affiliation. Further, for Māori with an iwi affiliation, we stratify by whether they live in an area where their iwi has a strong network. Research has shown that each of these dimensions of ethnic identity can have important effects on both labour market outcomes and mobility decisions (Palloni et al. 2001; Carrington et al. 1996; Kritz and Nogle 1994; Chapple 1999; Nikora et al. 2004). Finally, our analysis directly examines how individuals from different groups respond to changes in local labour market opportunities during the post-reform period.

In contrast to the anecdotal evidence, we find that Māori are more mobile on average than similar Europeans. However, Māori who live in areas with strong networks of their iwi (whom we refer to as ‘local’ Māori) are slightly less mobile than Europeans. The difference between Māori who live locally to their iwi and those who do not is even more pronounced when we consider responsiveness to local labour market shocks. Non-local Māori are considerably more responsive to changes in economic opportunities than are Europeans, whereas local Māori are almost entirely unresponsive.

Although this means that the migration responses to labour market shocks of Māori are, on average, roughly comparable to those of Europeans, it highlights the fact that there exists a large subpopulation of Māori whose location choices are almost entirely unaffected by labour market considerations. While 17 % of local Māori change labour market areas over a 5-year period, our analysis suggests that these moves are primarily driven by non-labour market considerations. This suggests that, for certain Māori, culture- or socially based ties to particular areas could be an important impediment to moving to labour market opportunities. These Māori are likely to have faced considerable difficulty adjusting to the reforms of the late 1980s and early 1990s.

While our study focuses on the mobility of Māori, our goal is to shed light on migration responses to labour market shocks more generally, especially among lower skilled individuals. Māori are not the only people who have networks of family, friends, and acquaintances that are centred in one location; however, the case of Māori is particularly amenable to empirical analysis because we can measure these networks using iwi affiliations. Extrapolating our results to other ethnicities suggests that migration decisions among the less skilled are nuanced. Within any ethnic group, there are likely to be both many individuals who are responsive to changes in economic opportunities and many who will not relocate in the face of negative shocks. Importantly, these groups are likely to be differently affected by economic policies that target particular regions and their relative size critical for determining the effectiveness of place-based policies.

The rest of the paper is organised as follows: Section 2 briefly discusses Māori socioeconomic structure and history and reviews the relevant literature; Section 3 describes the data used in the analysis and provides some sample characteristics; Section 4 presents results from our econometric estimation; and Section 5 concludes.

2 Background and relevant literature

2.1 BackgroundFootnote 1

‘Māori’ are defined in this paper, and generally in New Zealand research, as individuals who identify themselves with the Māori ethnicity, which is a measure of cultural affiliation, as opposed to race, ancestry, nationality, or citizenship. Ethnicity is self-perceived and people can belong to more than one ethnic group. The vast majority of Māori belong to an iwi, which can loosely be translated as tribe.Footnote 2 The iwi is traditionally the largest sociopolitical organisation in Māori society and is generally a territorial entity. Iwi members today retain strong ties to the rohe, or traditional region, of their iwi. As can be seen in Sin and Stillman (2005), this attachment to traditional lands has led to a large amount of geographic clustering among Māori. Hence, migration decisions are likely to be complicated by the issue of iwi affiliation, which is why we focus on this as an important source of heterogeneity.

At the time of initial European settlement in the early nineteenth century, the Māori economy was mainly agrarian. Introduced crops, such as potatoes, and metal implements were gradually incorporated into the economy, and over time, Māori increased their economic production and integration into the cash economy. By the late 1850s, a long-lasting economic decline for Māori had begun. Māori were strongly represented in the flour milling and shipping industries, and when these markets collapsed, the impact on Māori was significant. During this time, settlers and the Crown confiscated 18 million acres of land from Māori, which dramatically reduced their autonomy and their economic output.

The next period of large change came in the post-war period. In 1965, nearly two thirds of Māori lived in rural areas, but by 2006, nearly 85 % lived in urban areas (and hence many had moved away from their rohe). This urban migration often meant better opportunities for good housing, full-time employment, and education. As Māori were significantly under-represented in the higher levels of education, they became predominantly represented in low-skill occupations, such as factory work, forestry, and meat processing. These were exactly the areas that were most affected by the economic reforms of the 1980s.

2.2 Literature

Limited prior research has rigorously examined mobility among Māori.Footnote 3 Most relevant to our study is Vaithianathan (1995), which uses data from the 1991 census to examine the impact of local labour market opportunities on the mobility of Māori between 1986 and 1991 compared with that of non-Māori. She finds that while non-Māori migration is highly responsive to local labour market opportunities, Māori migration is much less responsive, particularly for Māori living in their traditional iwi area. While her results are consistent with our finding that local Māori are almost entirely unresponsive to changes in economic opportunities, our results suggest that mobility in response to economic opportunities has increased substantially for non-local Māori since the reform period. Given the general uncertainty associated with the reforms, especially for low-skilled individuals, it is perhaps unsurprising that mobility was initially lower for this group.

The mobility of minority groups has been the focus of a small international literature, though often in the context of residential segregation. South and Deane (1993) and Ross (1998) find that African Americans in the USA are less likely to move house than are other groups, even controlling for individual and area characteristics. They suggest that housing segregation could be a contributing factor and raise the concern that this limited mobility harms black opportunities. In Australia, Biddle and Yap (2010) find that Indigenous Australians are less mobile than comparable non-Indigenous people, while Kinfu (2005) finds that young adult Indigenous Australians, who are in the key years for their career development, are less mobile than the Australian population as a whole. None of these papers directly examine how mobility for minority groups responds to changes in local economic opportunities.

3 Data

This paper uses unit record data for the New Zealand population from the 1996, 2001, and 2006 censuses.Footnote 4 We restrict our analysis to the New Zealand-born European and Māori population aged 30–59. As discussed later in this section, our mobility measure refers retrospectively to the previous 5 years, so these individuals are as young as 25 at the beginning of the observation period. We focus on this age group because students and individuals nearing retirement tend to migrate for quite different reasons from working-aged people. We exclude individuals born outside New Zealand and individuals of non-Māori, non-European ethnicity from our analysis because we suspect that these people may also have different mobility patterns than the majority group of New Zealand-born Europeans.

Individuals can record up to three self-defined ethnicities on a census form. Our main comparison groups are Europeans, sole Māori, and mixed Māori. We define Europeans as all individuals who state that they are of European ethnicity, but are not of Māori ethnicity; sole Māori as all individuals who report Māori as their only ethnicity; and mixed Māori as all individuals who report Māori ethnicity and at least one other ethnicity. Europeans, as defined in this paper, may also report other non-Māori ethnicities. Out of the 2.1 million individuals in our pooled sample, 85 % are European, 10 % sole Māori, and 5 % mixed Māori.

Information is collected in each census about the current usual residential locations of individuals and their usual residential locations (including overseas) 5 years before the census date (i.e. at the time of the previous census).Footnote 5 The nature of these data means we are unable to track forward the movements of all people living in any one area at an earlier time but instead must look backwards and examine the location 5 years ago of all individuals currently in a particular location.Footnote 6 The location information is coded to the relatively fine census ‘area unit’ level which in urban areas more or less corresponds to particular suburbs.Footnote 7 Because a high proportion of moves between area units are short-distance residential moves that do not relate to changes in labour market opportunities, our analysis focuses instead on moves between larger local labour market areas (LMAs). These 140 LMAs are commuting zones constructed by Papps and Newell (2002) using travel-to-work data from the 1991 census.Footnote 8

The census asks individuals with Māori ancestry to list up to five iwi affiliations.Footnote 9 As discussed above, migration decisions are likely to be complicated by the issue of iwi affiliation. Hence, we further classify Māori based on whether they specify any iwi affiliations and, if specified, whether or not they live in an LMA that is a ‘local area’ of any iwi with which they are affiliated.Footnote 10 A LMA is defined as local for an individual if the proportion of the total population of their iwi living there is 1.5 times larger than the proportion of the total European population living there as measured in a pooled sample of the 1996, 2001, and 2006 censuses.Footnote 11

4 Empirical strategy and results

4.1 Māori mobility between 1996 and 2006

We start by examining descriptively the mobility of the Māori population between 1996 and 2001 and between 2001 and 2006 compared with the mobility of the European population. We categorise each individual’s mobility status by comparing her current residence with her residence 5 years ago. Mobility status can take the values: (i) same area unit (AU), (ii) same LMA but different AU, (iii) different LMA, and (iv) moved from overseas. Moves within the same AU and within the same LMA but different AU are likely to be residential moves, as opposed to labour market moves. We initially present results broken down in this manner, but beyond these focus our analysis on moves that involve a change in LMA.

Panel A of Table 1 summarises the average mobility of our three main comparison population groups. Europeans exhibit similar local residential mobility to Māori, but Māori appear to be, on average, slightly more likely to move to a new LMA than Europeans in both sample periods. For example, between 1996 and 2001, 21 % of both sole and mixed Māori moved to a new LMA compared with 17 % of Europeans. Similar figures for between 2001 and 2006 are 22 % for sole and mixed Māori and 19 % for Europeans, respectively. Moves from overseas, considered a change in LMA, are a small part of overall mobility; Māori are slightly less likely to have moved from overseas.

Table 1 Mobility status by ethnicity, location, and year

Panel B compares mobility rates across subgroups of the Māori population defined by whether they specify any iwi affiliations and, if specified, whether or not at the beginning of the sample period they live in a local LMA as defined above. Sole and mixed Māori are combined for this analysis. In 1996, 44 % of Māori live in local iwi areas, 32 % live in non-local areas, and the remainder have no iwi affiliation. In 2001, 45 % live in local areas and 36 % live in non-local areas. In both periods, Māori living in a local iwi area are 8–10 percentage points less likely to move to a different LMA than Māori living in a non-local iwi area. Māori with no iwi affiliation fall somewhere in between. In general, Māori not living in a local iwi area appear quite a bit more mobile than Europeans (as measured by the percentage changing LMA).

Panel B also examines whether Māori who change LMAs move to local or non-local destination LMAs. Among Māori who live in a local LMA at the beginning of the sample period, 57–58 % of those who move between LMAs move to another local LMA, compared with 45–46 % of Māori movers who initially live in non-local LMAs. This suggests that Māori who live in local LMAs have a natural propensity to live in local iwi areas, as well as possibly having attachment to a particular local area. It is also possible that Māori who live in local LMAs are affiliated with iwi that are local to more LMAs, in general, than other Māori.

The finding that Māori are more mobile than Europeans on average appears at odds with the suggestion that the attachment of Māori to particular geographical locations renders them less mobile. However, these comparisons do not control for differences in the sociodemographic characteristics of the three ethnic groups. The Māori working-age population is younger than the European population, and younger people are typically more mobile than older ones. Other salient differences exist between the ethnic groups, for example, in educational levels and employment rates, which may also be correlated with mobility.

These raw comparisons also do not control for differences in where individuals are located. The likelihood that an individual leaves an area may partly be driven by characteristics of the area, such as amenities. Consequently, if people with a certain innate likelihood of being mobile tend to settle in particular areas, failing to account for the geographical clustering of ethnic groups could result in misleading conclusions about ethnic differences in mobility.

4.2 Regression analysis of ethnic mobility differences

For these reasons, we turn next to regression analysis so we can control for other important correlates with migration decisions and directly examine the impact of local economic shocks. Our main regression is a linear probability regression that takes the formFootnote 12

$$ {Y}_{it}={\alpha}_t+\beta {X}_{it}+\delta {Z}_{it}+\kern0.37em {e}_{it} $$
(1)

where i indexes the individual and t indexes the survey year. Y it equals 1 if individual i at time t lives in a different LMA to where he lived 5 years ago and equals 0 otherwise, X it is a vector of indicator variables that identify the ethnic group to which the individual belongs, and Z it is a vector of sociodemographic control variables the varies in different specifications. In all cases, we pool data from the 2001 and 2006 censuses and control for the survey year (α t ). The coefficients on the X it variables indicate the average underlying differences in mobility between individuals in different comparison groups and are the main focus of our analysis.

Our main regression analysis splits the Māori and European population into seven ethnic comparison groups: Europeans, sole Māori who live in a local LMA at the beginning of the sample period, sole Māori who live in a non-local LMA at the beginning of the sample period, sole Māori who do not report an iwi affiliation, and three analogous groups for mixed Māori.

Table 2 presents summary statistics for all variables used in the regression analyses for each comparison group. Europeans make up 85 % of the analysis population. Sole Māori in local LMAs are the largest Māori group (32 % of the Māori population) followed by sole Māori in non-local LMAs (19 %), mixed Māori in non-local LMAs (14 %), mixed Māori in local LMAs (13 %), sole Māori with no iwi affiliation (12 %), and mixed Māori with no iwi affiliation (9 %). Sociodemographic characteristics vary considerably across comparison groups. On average, Māori are younger, less qualified, less likely to be married, less likely to be in full-time employment, more likely to have low levels of income, and more likely to be single parents. In general, mixed Māori are more similar to Europeans than are sole Māori, and non-local Māori are more similar to Europeans than are local Māori.

Table 2 Population characteristics by ethnicity and location

Table 3 presents the results from estimating three versions of Eq. (1). Europeans are the omitted comparison group in each specification; thus, the coefficient on each other group is interpreted as the relative difference in mobility between that group and Europeans. In the first specification, we control for fixed or predetermined characteristics only, namely age (as a quadratic), gender, education, and survey year, in addition to the comparison group indicator variables.Footnote 13

Table 3 OLS regression of whether moved LMA from 5 years ago

Controlling for these basic characteristics, we find that all non-local Māori and those without an iwi affiliation are more mobile than Europeans while local Māori are less or similarly mobile. Local Māori are 0–2 percentage points less mobile, Māori with no iwi affiliation about 2 percentage points more mobile, non-local mixed Māori 6 percentage points more mobile, and non-local sole Māori 10 percentage points more mobile than comparable Europeans. Given our large sample size, all of these differences are strongly significant.

Figure 1 graphs the age-mobility relationship derived from the regression estimates (normalised to 0 for age 40). The solid line (no LMA FE) shows the results from the first specification. As expected, mobility decreases at a decreasing rate throughout the prime-age range, levelling off around age 52. The age-mobility gradient is quite steep early on, with 30-year-olds nearly 14 percentage points more likely to change LMAs than 40-year-olds. We also find a large education-mobility gradient. Relative to those with no qualifications, individuals with school qualifications are 0.3 percentage points more likely, those with vocational qualifications 2 percentage points more likely, and those with university degrees 7 percentage points more likely to change LMAs. Gender is essentially unrelated to mobility, with the difference between men and women economically zero (though statistically significant).

Fig. 1
figure 1

Estimated age-mobility patterns. Note: This figure shows the age-mobility relationships (normalised to 0 at age 40) in the regressions presented in Table 3

In the second specification, we control for an individual’s location 5 year’s previously (using LMA fixed effects measured at the beginning of the sample period) in addition to the control variables from the first specification. As previously discussed, these fixed effects capture the unobserved contributions of individual locations to outward mobility. Importantly, these fixed effects also capture differential impacts of the 1980s economic reforms across geographic areas. The impacts of the reforms mainly varied because of differences in local industrial structure and other local factors, such as demographics. These underlying differences are captured by the LMA fixed effects.

Our results are here inferred by comparing the mobility of Māori in particular locations to the mobility of similar Europeans in those same locations. This approach reduces the concern that any differences we might find are related to earlier locational decisions of Māori and non-Māori, including those related to the impact of the economic reforms, and not to underlying mobility propensities.

The comparisons between Europeans and the various Māori groups are qualitatively robust to the inclusion of LMA fixed effects. However, the coefficients on Māori groups decrease with LMA fixed effects, indicating that Māori tend to cluster in higher mobility LMAs. Non-local Māori are still much more mobile than Europeans, with mixed Māori in this group 4 percentage points more mobile, and sole Māori 8 percentage points more mobile. Māori with no iwi affiliation are now 1 percentage point more mobile and local Māori 1–2 percentage points less mobile than Europeans.Footnote 14 The age-mobility (the dashed lines in Fig. 1, labelled ‘LMA FE’) and education-mobility gradients are both flatter with the addition of LMA fixed effects. This indicates that younger individuals and those with more education choose to live in locations that people are more likely to leave (and vice versa for older individuals and those with less education).

In the third specification, we include control variables for an individual’s marital and employment status, family type, and pre-tax income in the previous year in addition to those variables included in the second specification. The backward-looking nature of our data means we are only able to measure these individual time-varying characteristics at the end of the period, after the individual has or has not moved. Because these variables are likely to be endogenously determined with mobility, their inclusion in the regression model may bias the results, and so our preferred specification excludes them. In fact, the inclusion of these additional control variables has little impact on our main findings.Footnote 15

4.3 Heterogeneity by ethnic group

The regression specifications estimated above assume that sociodemographic characteristics have the same effect on mobility for all comparison groups. Here, we re-estimate the second specification from Table 3, allowing the relationships between age, gender, and education and mobility to vary for each ethnic group. Table 4 presents the coefficients from one regression that includes all these interactions. The first column, labelled ‘Europeans’, shows the relationship between these variables and the mobility of Europeans. The remaining columns present interaction effects for each Māori group, i.e. these coefficients show the effect of each characteristic on the mobility of a particular Māori subgroup over and above its effect on Europeans.

Table 4 OLS regressions of whether individuals moved LMA from 5 years ago with ethnicity interaction effects

Figure 2 graphs the age-mobility profiles of Māori relative to Europeans.Footnote 16 This figure shows that most types of Māori are most mobile relative to Europeans at mid-working ages of 40 to 45 and have lower relative mobility both at young and old working ages. We also find that the relationship between education and mobility differs across ethnic groups. The interaction effects show consistent evidence that mobility is higher for more qualified individuals and that this difference is more pronounced for most Māori groups than for Europeans.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Estimated age-mobility patterns by ethnicity. Note: This figure shows the age-mobility profiles of different groups of Māori relative to Europeans in the regression presented in Table 4. Refer to the notes to Table 1 for an explanation of how local and non-local Māori are defined

The qualification-mobility gradient is particularly steep for local Māori. For example, local Māori with university degrees are 8.6 percentage points more mobile than local Māori with no qualifications, whereas this difference for Europeans is just 4 percentage points. Combining these figures with the average differences between local Māori and Europeans discussed above, local Māori with university degrees are clearly more mobile in absolute terms than comparable Europeans. This may reflect that Māori with higher qualifications are a more select group of the population than equivalently qualified Europeans, which is quite likely given the lower average qualification levels of Māori.

4.4 Impact of labour market shocks

In this section, we extend our basic regression model, Eq. (1), to include controls for local economic conditions. Specifically, we control for the labour force participation rate (LFP), the unemployment rate, and the interaction between the two among people of the same age and education level as the individual and who lived in the individual’s origin LMA. Labour market conditions are all measured 5 years previously, at the beginning of the migration period.Footnote 17 Since we include origin LMA fixed effects, we are effectively asking how mobility responds to changes in local economic opportunities. We control for both local LFP and unemployment rates, as well as their interaction, to allow people in and out of the labour force to have different average migration responses to local labour market shocks. A range of factors could cause such heterogeneity. For example, a strong labour market might make a region attractive to a worker, but more expensive for a non-worker. More broadly, those who are in the labour force might have their location decisions driven by different factors to those who are not. For example, those outside the labour force may not be able to afford the monetary cost or risk of migration.

Table 5 presents the results of this regression. To aid interpretation of the interactions, in Fig. 3, we graph the impact of changes in the unemployment rate on the mobility of different ethnic groups at different levels of local LFP. These results show that higher unemployment rates for a demographic group in a region lead to higher out migration by Europeans in that demographic group when local LFP for that group is over 50 %. The magnitude of this effect is increasing in the group’s LFP, with a 10 percentage point increase in unemployment leading to a 0.3 percentage point increase in migration when LFP is 50 % compared with a 2.9 percentage point increase in migration when LFP is 100 %. The difference between these effects has the expected sign: individuals in the labour force are more likely to leave an area when it suffers a negative labour demand shock, whereas individuals not in the labour force are less likely to be induced to leave by such a shock.

Table 5 OLS regressions of whether individuals moved LMA from 5 years ago: impact of labour market shocks
Fig. 3
figure 3

Estimated impact of local unemployment rates on mobility by ethnicity. Note: This figure shows the impact of changes in the unemployment rate on the mobility of different ethnic groups at different levels of local labour force participation, from the regression presented in Table 5. Refer to the notes to Table 1 for an explanation of how local and non-local Māori are defined

Both groups of non-local Māori are highly responsive to labour market conditions. This could be because these individuals are disproportionately likely to have moved in the past to pursue employment away from their home areas, and as such are self-selected to be more mobile for non-family reasons. Like Europeans, non-local mixed Māori are more responsive at higher levels of LFP but have relatively higher out-mobility at every LFP level. Non-local sole Māori are more responsive to labour market shocks than Europeans at low levels of LFP, but their responsiveness is insignificantly different to that of Europeans at high levels of LFP.

In contrast, both groups of local Māori are both very unresponsive to labour market conditions, and this unresponsiveness does not vary significantly with LFP. This could occur because this group has chosen to live ‘locally’ for non-economic reasons and hence will likely move only if these reasons change (for example, if family circumstances change). Alternatively, their local support networks might be strong enough to help them weather temporary adverse shocks to economic opportunities, alleviating their need to move.

We cannot reject the hypothesis that mixed Māori without iwi affiliations are equally responsive to local economic shocks as Europeans, which makes sense since this group is likely to be the most ‘European’ of the Māori groups. Our results for sole Māori without iwi affiliations are difficult to interpret. They show counter-intuitively that these Māori are less likely to leave a labour market area that faces a negative economic shock, especially if local LFP is high. One possibility is that the quality of data for these individuals is lower than for other groups, potentially including higher mis-recall of location 5 years earlier.Footnote 18

5 Conclusions

In this paper, we use census data to examine how the internal mobility of Māori compares to that of Europeans in New Zealand from 1996 to 2006. Our regression analysis compares the mobility between geographic labour markets of Māori and Europeans who initially live in the same area. We also examine heterogeneity in outcomes within the Māori population, distinguishing Māori who report only one ethnicity from those with multiple ethnicities and those who report a tribal (iwi) affiliation. For Māori with an iwi affiliation, we also stratify by whether they live in an area where their iwi has a strong network. Finally, our analysis directly examines how individuals from different groups responded to changes in local labour market opportunities during the post-reform period.

In contrast to most anecdotal evidence, we find that Māori are more mobile on average than similar Europeans. However, Māori who live in areas with strong networks of their iwi are slightly less mobile than Europeans, suggesting that social ties could be an important impediment to moving to labour market opportunities. Our findings on migration responses to local labour market shocks provide additional evidence along these lines: Māori living in their iwi network areas are almost entirely unresponsive to changes in local economic opportunities. In contrast, non-local Māori are more responsive than Europeans.

Although self-selection is likely to play a role in these differences, they do imply that there exists a large sub-population of Māori who are likely to have had trouble adjusting to the reforms of the 1980s liberalisation period. This also suggests that there may be an important role for location-based policies in closing the gap between Māori and European labor market outcomes.

Notes

  1. The material in this section comes from Consedine (2007) and Statistics New Zealand (2014).

  2. There are 111 iwi recognised by Te Puni Kōkiri (Ministry of Māori Affairs). Statistics New Zealand (2014) reports that 89 % of Māori adults know their iwi.

  3. A number of papers, including Kerr et al. (2001), Maré and Timmins (2004), and Maré and Choy (2001), examine internal mobility in New Zealand using aggregate data, but are unable to analyse differences between population groups. Renkow and Scrimgeour (2005) use grouped data from the 1996 and 2001 censuses to study the relative mobility of Māori between 1991 and 2001. Inconsistent with the previous literature and our work, they find no evidence of a link between worker mobility and local labour market conditions for either Māori or non-Māori. We suspect this occurs because they are examining mobility at a quite aggregated geographical level (between 16 regional councils) using a gravity model and hence have little variation in their measures of local labour market conditions, as well as limited controls for other important regional differences.

  4. In a previous version of the paper, we also examined mobility between 1991 and 1996, with similar patterns found as in the later periods we now focus on. The 1986 census is the first one with unit record data available for research, but the 1991 census was the first to collect data on iwi affiliation. In an unpublished Appendix available from the authors, we show that relative ethnic mobility patterns have remained similar over time.

  5. A negligible number of individuals are dropped because their usual residential address is unavailable.

  6. It is not possible to calculate the precise probability that a person living in a certain location moved, as some of the people previously living in that location will not have filled out a census form 5 years later for various reasons. For example, they may have died, moved overseas, or failed to fill out their census forms in enough detail for their previous addresses to be ascertained. The probabilities that we do calculate (of people moving when we know both their current and previous addresses) are likely to be understated relative to the true probabilities of moves, because the most mobile people are the most likely to be missed or to have an incomplete address record from 5 years ago. We are also not able to identify multiple moves over the 5-year period.

  7. There are nearly 2000 area units in New Zealand, with an average of 2000 individuals living in each.

  8. Papps and Newell (2002) construct LMAs using an algorithm that ensures that most people who live in one LMA work in it and most people who work in one LMA live in it. Their algorithm requires LMAs to have a minimum employed population of 2000 and 75 % containment of workers. LMAs have been used as the geographical units of interests in a wide range of papers on mobility in New Zealand, such as Maré and Timmins (2004) and Maré and Stillman (2010).

  9. Iwi do not have to conform to any particular specifications in terms of size or other characteristics and are an evolving set. For example, SNZ periodically reviews its list of iwi, considering new possibilities for iwi in terms of a number of guidelines. At the time of the 2001 census, it recognised approximately 95 individual iwi. Of these, 13 had more than 10,000 members, 14 had between 5000 and 10,000, 32 had between one and five thousand and 36 had fewer than one thousand members.

  10. Māori without an iwi affiliation are a heterogenous group including individuals reporting Māori ethnicity but not Māori ancestry, Māori who report an iwi affiliation that cannot be classified by SNZ, Māori who do not answer the iwi affiliation question, and Māori who truly do not have an iwi affiliation.

  11. We experimented with other cut-offs; more broadly defined local areas lessened the mobility differences between local and non-local Māori.

  12. This model is a reduced-form specification of the general internal migration model introduced in Greenwood (1975). We estimate an OLS model even though we have a binary dependent variable because, as discussed in Angrist and Pischke (2009), if one’s goal is to estimate marginal effects, then this model is robust to misspecification of the conditional distribution of the error term, whereas discrete choice models are not. Interpretation of the results is also more straightforward, particularly when there are two-way interactions as in some of our specifications. We also estimate models where our outcome variable is distance moved and have similar qualitative findings.

  13. Although education is not, strictly speaking, fixed or predetermined, the 30- to 59-year-olds who make up our sample had largely completed their formal education more than 5 years earlier.

  14. Our results are robust to including as control variables change in both population and employment between 1986 and 1991 at the LMA level (as in Stillman et al. 2010) instead of origin LMA fixed effects. These two variables capture the immediate impact of the economic reforms on the LMA. As expected, we find that out-migration is much higher in LMAs that had larger declines in either population or employment between 1986 and 1991. These results and those mentioned in the next footnote are available from the authors by request.

  15. We also estimate a specification that includes industry and occupation fixed effects for employed individuals. While we believe that these are likely important determinants of how economic shocks impact individuals, we can only measure these variables at the end of the census period and hence they are likely endogenously determined with the mobility decision. Again, this has little qualitative impact on our results.

  16. Note, the age-mobility pattern is a similar U-shape for all Māori groups; the values in Fig. 2 illustrate differences in the concavity of the age-mobility relationship by ethnic group.

  17. We experimented with different measures of demographic characteristics. Because some LMAs are quite small, we settled on a version based on 10-year age groups and three qualification categories (grouping degree with post-school). Our regression also includes fixed effects for these 30 groups.

  18. This would be consistent with not listing any iwi indicating, in some cases, a lack of effort in filling out the census form rather than a genuine lack of affiliation.

References

  • Angrist JD, Pischke J-S. Mostly harmless econometrics: an empiricist’s companion. Princeton: Princeton University Press; 2009.

    Google Scholar 

  • Biddle N, Yap M. Demographic and socioeconomic outcomes across the Indigenous Australian lifecourse: evidence from the 2006 census, CAEPR Research Monograph, vol. 31. 2010.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carrington WJ, Detragiache E, Vishwanath T. Migration with endogenous moving costs. Am Econ Rev. 1996;86(4):909–30.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chapple S. Explaining patterns of disparity between Mäori and non-Mäori employment chances. Labour Market Bulletin. 1999;1999:70–100.

    Google Scholar 

  • Consedine B. Historical influences: Māori and the economy. Te Puni Kōkiri: Wellington; 2007.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dixon S. Growth in the dispersion of earnings: 1984–97. Labour Market Bulletin. 1998;1998(1&2):71–107.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greenwood MJ. Research on internal migration in the United States. J Econ Lit. 1975;13:397–433.

    Google Scholar 

  • Karagedikli Ö, Maré DC, Poot J. Disparities and despair: changes in regional income distributions in New Zealand 1981–1996. Australas J Reg Stud. 2000;6(3):323–47.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kinfu, Y. Spatial mobility among Indigenous Australians: patterns and determinants. Demography and Sociology Program, Australian National University. 2005.

  • Kritz MM, Nogle JM. Nativity concentration and internal migration among the foreign-born. Demography. 1994;31(3):509–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maré DC, Choy W-K. Regional labour market adjustment and the movement of people, Treasury Working Paper. 2001.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maré DC, Stillman S. The impact of immigration on the geographic mobility of New Zealanders. Economic Record. 2010;86(273):247–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maré DC, and Timmins J. “Internal Migration and Regional Labour Markets In New Zealand” Paper presented to the NZAE Conference, Wellington, 2004.

  • Nikora LW, Guerin B, Rua M, Te Awekotuku N. Moving away from home: some social consequences for Tuhoe migrating to the Waikato. New Zealand Popul Rev. 2004;30(1&2):93–109.

    Google Scholar 

  • Palloni A, Massey DS, Ceballos M, Espinosa K, Spittel M. Social capital and international migration: a test using information on family networks. Am J Sociol. 2001;106(5):1262–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Papps KL, Newell JO. Identifying functional labour market areas in New Zealand: a reconnaissance study using travel-to-work data, IZA Discussion Paper, vol. 443. 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  • Renkow M, and Scrimgeour F. “Māori/Non-Māori income gaps: do differences in worker mobility play arole?”. Selected Paper prepared for presentation at the American Agricultural Economics Association Annual Meeting, Providence, Rhode Island, 2005.

  • Ross SL. Racial differences in residential and job mobility: evidence concerning the spatial mismatch hypothesis. J Urban Econ. 1998;43(1):112–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sin I, Stillman S. The geographical mobility of Māori in New Zealand, Motu Working Paper. 2005.

    Google Scholar 

  • South SJ, Deane GD. Race and residential mobility: individual determinants and structural constraints. Soc Forces. 1993;72(1):147–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Statistics New Zealand. Te Kupenga 2013 Fact Sheet. Wellington: Statistics New Zealand; 2014.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stillman S, Velamuri M, Aitken A. The long-run impact of New Zealand’s structural reform on local communities. J Comp Econ. 2010;38(4):432–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vaithianathan, Rhema. 1995. The impact of regional unemployment and iwi (tribal) affiliation on internal migration. Master’s thesis, School of Commerce and Economics, University of Auckland.

  • Walker RJ. Struggle without end (Ka Whawhai Ttonu Matou). Auckland: Penguin; 1990.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank Dave Maré, Amelie Constant (editor), the anonymous referee, and seminar audiences at Motu Economic and Public Policy Research, the Population Association of New Zealand conference, and the New Zealand Association of Economists conference for useful comments on the paper. We also thank Nathan Chappell for excellent research assistance and James Newell for providing us with data and assistance in creating local labour market boundaries. Most of the work on this paper was done while Stillman was employed at the University of Otago, Dunedin, New Zealand.

Responsible editor: Amelie Constant.

Disclaimer

Access to the data used in this study was provided by Statistics New Zealand under conditions designed to give effect to the security and confidentiality provisions of the Statistics Act 1975. All non-regression results are subject to base three rounding in accordance with Statistics New Zealand’s release policy for census data. The project was originally funded as part of Motu’s “Understanding Adjustment and Inequality” research programme, which had core funding from the Foundation for Research, Science and Technology. Any views expressed are the sole responsibility of the authors and do not purport to represent those of Motu, the Free University of Bozen-Bolzano, or Statistics New Zealand.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Steven Stillman.

Additional information

Competing interests

The IZA Journal of Migration is committed to the IZA Guiding Principles of Research Integrity. The authors declare that they have observed these principles.

Additional file

Additional file 1:

Online appendices. (PDF 75 kb)

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Sin, I., Stillman, S. Economic liberalisation and the mobility of minority groups: evidence from Māori in New Zealand. IZA J Migration 5, 4 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1186/s40176-016-0049-z

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1186/s40176-016-0049-z

Keywords